En
route to Boston the other weekend, I was hoping to get some work done during my
layover in LaGuardia. Rather than finding unlimited free Wi-Fi as I’d been
expecting, I discovered that only the first 30 minutes were free. As a
cash-strapped college student, I decided I’d do what I could offline and then
connect for the 30 minutes if needed. When I finally connected to the free
network, I was unable to access anything. I wasn’t entirely surprised, given
the amount of traffic that LaGuardia must see on a typical day – 38,000 through
Delta’s two terminals alone, according to this
estimate.
It
later dawned on me that this was an example of private markets acting to more
efficiently allocate a public good. While free Wi-Fi is not a pure public good,
it is non-excludable and as non-rivalrous as the capability of the server
allows. Public Wi-Fi is non-excludable because there is no password and/or
price, thus anyone nearby can connect. However, public Wi-Fi is not purely
non-rivalrous. The speed of the network will slow down as more people connect,
inhibiting the ability of those already connected to “consume” the Wi-Fi. With
only one public network, users who are scrolling through Facebook and Instagram
constrain the ability of those trying to utilize the network for work. When one
considers the individual utilities of such proxy groups, SMC probably exceeds
SMB. Thus, by imposing a cost to access Wi-Fi beyond 30 minutes - and an
even higher cost if you want extra high-speed internet - the market allocates
the good more efficiently. Thanks to this market mechanism, I was able to write
a cover letter in record time. I wasn’t about to shell out $10+ knowing that
I’d likely end up being the mindless millennial scrolling through her social
media feeds.
What I would’ve tweeted
@LaGuardia airport had I decided to pay: being able to connect to but not actually
utilize a wireless network does not constitute “free Wi-Fi.”
No comments:
Post a Comment